Kelly Peters' keynote talk at BlockHack Global focused on the topic of consumer technology adoption. In many cases, developers and organizations build a solution anticipating droves of consumer interest, only to find that unanticipated barriers are curbing uptake rates.
In her talk, she provides an overview of BE for blockchain developers looking to overcome adoption challenges at the very outset of their conceptual stage. She shares some key behavioural insights that can be used to understand how people typically make decisions, and how they can apply these lessons to overcome the most common pitfalls facing adoption today.
Watch the full recording below
Here are some excerpts from the talk:
A small simple change in our language can change our thinking. When we start off a sentence with “I think that...”, we state it as if it is fact. It’s got baggage around it—our opinion, our ego—and it inhibits our ability to receive feedback. On the contrary, when we start off a sentence with “it is my hypothesis that...”, it implies that we are still gathering evidence and our minds can be changed based on new evidence. This type of thinking allows people to go deeper with their thinking and has a data-seeking orientation.
This views people as robots where people would predictably act a particular way given a particular stimulus, but as we know from behavioural economics, people are not truly maximizers. Maybe early adopters of blockchain are more likely to be maximizing beings, but the general population is likely less so.
Knowing this, when designing products and services for blockchain, designers should hang on to value propositions of blockchain, such as decentralization, as a Hippocratic Oath but also appreciate that most people are boundedly rational.
Behavioural Economics is not saying that we’re either rational or irrational, but rather that we’re boundedly rational–that we can be limited by constraints, such as time and energy. Consequently, we use heuristics (i.e., mental shortcuts) to inform our decisions and shape our understanding of what is good or bad, easy or hard, what’s trustworthy or untrustworthy.
If you assume your users are relying on System 1, then they are relying on heuristics when engaging with your platform. However, heuristics are not necessarily always rational and they are not always the best guides for our decision-making.
For example, people may be prone to frequency illusion. When you are looking to buy a car, you may “see” that car more often. This can lead to confirmation bias, confirming your preconceptions of the popularity of car, although in reality, the car may not be as popular as you think. Alternatively, you may seek the expertise of a friend. However, there may be a halo effect, in which you view their opinion more positively, or they may have an undisclosed conflict of interest.
Thus, when designing, you need to keep in mind the type of thinking users are engaging in. If users are engaging in System 1 thinking, then they may be prone to biases. If user are engaging in System 2 thinking, then designs must account for users’ limited cognitive abilities.
For example, we can use biases to help people save more for retirement. For retirement savings plan, it makes sense for people to invest in their savings because of reductions in taxes and some employers would match investments. But participation is low at about 15-20%. How come?
We have to look into the human experience of thinking of retirement and savings. There’s cognitive overload when enrolling in these programs—so many documents to go through and forms to fill out. The traditional approach is to educate workers through seminars. These seminars seem to be effective at changing workers’ beliefs about retirement savings, as one study demonstrated that more than 80% said yes to enrolling, however, most did not follow through.
Thus, a proven strategy is to use defaults with the option to opt-out, which help people save while maintaining the autonomy of choice. As it turns out, the use of defaults resulted in over 90% of people stay enrolled. From a libertarian standpoint, this strategy is ethical, as people still have free choice to opt-out.
Subsequently, they reversed the ratings of the songs, where the ranked #1 song was now the last song, and the ranked #2 was now the second-last song, and so forth. Then, with a new group of participants, the researchers exposed them to this music market with this new reversed list.
In this new social world, people were influenced by the ratings, in which the popular songs were downloaded the most, and the least popular songs were downloaded the least. However, over the long run, the popular songs in the original rating became more popular, while the least popular songs in the original rating became the least less popular. This study demonstrated the potential powerful influence of social context on decisions.
In this phase, we try to understand and segment the users based on their decision-making and behaviours. We can design products and services by segmenting users into rational thinkers or heuristics thinkers.
Leveraging biases, such as status quo and defaults, to nudge people to behave in a particular manner.
This is where we generate evidence to test our hypothesis.
The TAM framework is broken down into two main parts. The first is the utility of the technology, which is perceived usefulness. The second is cost of use, which is the perceived ease of use. These two factors influence attitudes of using the technology and users’ attitudes help determine adoption.
If people do not trust the technology, they would be less likely to adopt it. We can counter lack of trust with operational transparency, which is where users are shown the hidden processes underlying a service/product. For example, in a study using kayak.com, it was found that when the search process was slowed down to show effort, users’ perception of value went up.
As mentioned, people like to stick with the status quo. One way to counter status quo is with habit disruption, which is to introduce something new when people have a change in habit.
Q (1:03:00): There’s so many choices in blockchain. Is it on us as developers to weed out the many options?
A: When there are so many choices, there is a risk of exposing users to choice overload, which dissuades them from making a decision.
Iyengar led a study about choice overload using jams. Note that this specific study did not replicate but it is relevant to our discussion.
This study was set up in a grocery store, where customers could sample jams. In one setup, there were 6 choices of jam and in a separate setup, there were 24 choices of jams. It was found that significant more people bought a jam when they were exposed to 6 jams as opposed to 24 jams. So more people acted when there were fewer choices.
So how can this be applied? You can use clustering and have a triage
mechanism, in which people can choose based on features of a product. For example, a jam can be split into sugar or sugar free and so forth. It is the same thing in the investment world. With so many names, people either don’t choose at all or they choose investment based on names, which is not rational.
Q (1:08:50): What is the FOMO (Fear Of Missing Out) role in influencing our decisions? It is not rational but very human trait.
A: This is a classic example of the scarcity effect. Salespeople use this tactic to drive sales by leveraging limited time. Scarcity is based on loss aversion, in which people typically are driven by not wanting to lose something, and that is a powerful motivator. There are psychological taxes that can influenced behaviour, such as fear, guilt, regret, and shame. These behavioural influences should be used for good, ethical outcomes.
Q (1:11:00): Are there traps and pitfalls that you’ve noticed that designers fall into when designing Blockchain products and services?